Big Tech Firms Like Facebook, Amazon, and Google Are Not Monopolies

by | Feb 9, 2022

Meta (Facebook), Amazon, Apple, Alphabet (Google), and other Big Tech companies are not monopolies. They have achieved their dominance through competition. Success through competition is a part of competition.
Image Pixabay

Meta (Facebook), Amazon, Apple, Alphabet (Google), and other Big Tech companies are not monopolies.  They have achieved their dominance through competition in the marketplace by being more innovative and efficient.  Success through competition is a part of competition.  It does not create monopoly.

The essential characteristic of monopolies

The belief these firms are monopolies stems from the popular view that a monopoly is a single large, dominant seller.  However, the popular view does not provide a good understanding of monopoly because it lumps together organizations that achieved their dominance by being protected from competition by the government with firms that achieved their dominance through competition.

This poor understanding of monopoly has its roots in early monopolies, such as the British East India Company and the French Mississippi Company.  These companies were granted monopolies by their respective governments.  They were often large, dominant sellers of goods.  But they did not achieve their positions through competition; they were granted sole-supplier positions through government decree.

It is the government protection, not the large single-seller characteristic, that is essential to monopoly.  It is this characteristic that leads to inefficiency, higher prices, and lower quality goods.  Economic competition refers chiefly to a business producing a product and getting people to buy it voluntarily.  It includes, among other things, building better products than your rivals or potential rivals, effectively marketing and advertising your products and company, and keeping your costs low.  This is what the Nobel Prize-winning economist F.A. Hayek referred to in his theory of competition based on rivalry among producers.

Monopoly, properly understood, refers to the government initiating physical force—using compulsion and coercion—to restrict firms’ ability to engage in the competitive process.  Monopoly power can be created through licensing laws, government subsidies, exclusive government franchises (such as for utility companies), government-owned organizations, tariffs, quotas, and other means.

Moreover, multiple smaller businesses can have a monopoly against a large business.  For example, before the rise of the internet, ordinances restricting the size of retailers in some areas granted monopoly power to smaller retailers at the expense of large retailers like Walmart.  These laws effectively prevented Walmart from entering some areas (or forced it to build smaller stores) and thus forcibly restricted Walmart’s ability to compete.

Walmart was not a monopoly as many people believe; it was the victim of monopoly.  Walmart earned its dominance through competition by being more efficient than its rivals.  And what is true for Walmart is true in general.  For companies to dominate through competition, they must be more efficient and innovative than their rivals and they must more effectively provide goods that people want to buy.

A proper economic concept of monopolies

A proper concept of monopoly cannot lump together achieving dominance through competition with obtaining a dominant position through restrictions of competition by the government.  These two means of achieving a dominant position are fundamentally different.  The former involves achieving a dominant position by engaging in voluntary trade and respecting the rights and freedom of others.  The latter involves achieving a dominant position through violations of rights and freedom—i.e., through government compulsion and coercion.

Developing new products, improving upon existing products, developing and improving upon methods of production, keeping costs low, getting people to buy one’s products voluntarily, etc. require freedom and the protection of individual rights.  This is because using one’s mind to think and acting on one’s rational judgment requires freedom and the protection of individual rights.  In other words, the mind requires freedom to flourish.  Hence, freedom and the protection of rights are fundamental requirements of human life.  This, ultimately, is why these two different means of achieving dominance lead to radically different economic outcomes.

As an example of these different outcomes, consider the difference between the U.S. Post Office or Amtrak and the Big Tech firms.  The USPS is a large, dominant provider of mail.  But how has it achieved this position?  It has done so through protection by the government: through laws that restrict competition from private firms (such as the Post Office Clause in the Constitution) and through massive taxpayer subsidies.  As a result, the USPS is notorious for inefficiency and low-quality service.  The same is essentially true of Amtrak.

In contrast, the Big Tech firms have achieved their positions by being innovative and providing high-quality products and services.  Think of the incredible phones and computers produced by Apple or the amazing search engine developed by Google as examples.

Market competition requires laissez-faire capitalism

We need to maximize the number of firms that dominate through superior performance and minimize the number of organizations that are protected from competition.  But creating a competitive environment requires protecting the freedom of competition, which means protecting the freedom of firms to compete in any field they have both the means and ability to do business in.  This implies that the government must not intervene to protect large firms from competition, but it also must not punish firms that have been successful through competition.  The government must follow a policy of laissez-faire and let companies—both large and small—sink or swim on their own.

This government policy will help create a more dynamic, innovative, and rapidly progressing economy.  In such an economy, dominant firms cannot rest on their laurels.  They must continuously innovate to remain dominant.  Dominant firms are often challenged by smaller firms that expand their businesses by being innovative and efficient.  These companies sometimes become dominant themselves and are then challenged by newcomers.

So Sears and Montgomery Ward were challenged by Walmart, which is now being challenged by Amazon for the dominant retailer position.  IBM was challenged by Microsoft, which is being challenged by Apple and Google for dominance in the computer industry.  Ford was challenged by GM, which was eventually challenged by Toyota and others to be the largest automobile manufacturer.  As a result, products and services are improved and become more widely available.  But to maximize the benefits of this upward spiral, the freedom of competition for small and large firms alike must be protected.

Antitrust laws punish success

One mechanism used by the government to punish successful companies is the antitrust laws.  These laws impede competition by attacking some of the most competitive firms.  For example, they have been used throughout their history to punish innovators such as Standard Oil, DuPont, A&P, Alcoa, IBM, and Microsoft.  The federal government’s latest push to punish the Big Tech firms with these laws is merely a continuation of this harmful, anti-competitive practice.

By punishing the winners, we protect inefficient and ineffective organizations.  This leads to less intense competition, less innovation, lower rates of economic progress, and a lower standard of living than would otherwise exist for the average person in the economy.

Brian P. Simpson is an economics professor and chair of the Department of Accounting, Finance, and Economics in the College of Professional Studies at National University in La Jolla, CA. He is the author of A Declaration and Constitution for a Free Society, and the two-volume work on Austrian business cycle theory titled Money, Banking, and the Business Cycle (Palgrave Macmillan, 2014) and the book Markets Don’t Fail! (Lexington Books, 2005). Visit his website brian-simpson.com.

The views expressed above represent those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the editors and publishers of Capitalism Magazine. Capitalism Magazine sometimes publishes articles we disagree with because we think the article provides information, or a contrasting point of view, that may be of value to our readers.

Have a comment?

Post your response in our Capitalism Community on X.

Related articles

Misunderstanding the Meaning of a “Monopoly”

Misunderstanding the Meaning of a “Monopoly”

As long as government secures and protects private property rights, enforces all contracts entered into voluntarily and through mutual agreement, and assures law and order under an impartial rule of law, “monopoly” as an economic or social problem is virtually non-existent. But introduce government intervention into the market system, and monopoly invariably becomes a social harm and an economic problem.

The DOJ’s Coercive Case against Google

The DOJ’s Coercive Case against Google

One of the DOJ’s main criticisms is how Google established itself early on as the default search engine for Apple and Android products, yet doing so was simply shrewd business strategy. Anyone with the opportunity to do so would have done the same.

No spam. Unsubscribe anytime.

Pin It on Pinterest